Chat with us, powered by LiveChat In this article, the authors analyze the relationship between market concentration (using alternative measures of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI)) and hospital market - Writeedu

In this article, the authors analyze the relationship between market concentration (using alternative measures of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI)) and hospital market

600 words requirement

 In this article (see link to the article below), the authors analyze the relationship between market concentration (using alternative measures of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI)) and hospital market power (using a wage-adjusted hospital price index).  Their somewhat surprising finding is that most high-priced hospitals are located in the least concentrated markets (i.e. HHI < 2500).  In your discussion, I want you to focus on the policy implications of these results.  Specifically, are the recent federal legislative proposals described in the article to regulate hospital prices justified by the authors' findings?  The reasons for your answer may be based on features of the authors' study (such as the data or definitions of the measures used) as well as on factors or issues excluded from their analysis.  The authors discuss some excluded issues and factors, as well as limitations of their analysis, but you need not limit yourself to what is contained in the article.  However, limit yourself to two or three key reasons why the results presented in this article do or do not justify recent proposals to regulate high-priced hospitals.     

By Maximilian J. Pany, Michael E. Chernew, and Leemore S. Dafny

Regulating Hospital Prices Based On Market Concentration Is Likely To Leave High-Price Hospitals Unaffected

ABSTRACT Concern about high hospital prices for commercially insured patients has motivated several proposals to regulate these prices. Such proposals often limit regulations to highly concentrated hospital markets. Using a large sample of 2017 US commercial insurance claims, we demonstrate that under the market definition commonly used in these proposals, most high-price hospitals are in markets that would be deemed competitive or “moderately concentrated,” using antitrust guidelines. Limiting policy actions to concentrated hospital markets, particularly when those markets are defined broadly, would likely result in poor targeting of high-price hospitals. Policies that target the undesired outcome of high price directly, whether as a trigger or as a screen for action, are likely to be more effective than those that limit action based on market concentration.

H igh and rising hospital prices in commercial insurance markets pose a significant challenge for containing health care spend- ing.1 Given substantial evidence

that hospital consolidation causes price in- creases,2,3 federal and state agencies in the US have invested significant effort in investigating mergers and (in some cases) monitoring post- merger conduct.4 Authorities have also mounted challenges to practices such as anti-tiering and anti-steering provisions in contracts, which heighten the bargaining leverage of dominant health care systems.5 More recently, policy mak- ers and think tanks have introduced proposals to regulate prices directly in concentrated provider markets.6–8

The motivation for linking price regulation to market structure stems from the “structure- conduct-performance” (SCP) paradigm in eco- nomics,9 in which market structure, often mea- sured by the degree of market concentration among firms, directly affects the conduct of firms in the market, which in turn affects the

performance of that market (for example, the extent to which prices are “marked up” over costs). Yet there are important conceptual and measurement issues with this approach. Concep- tually, the link between structure and conduct is weak in many settings because of complex in- centives and institutional details. Duopolists may (implicitly or explicitly) collude or, alterna- tively, compete vigorously on price, depending on a range of factors outside of structure. In the case of hospitals, markets in which many pa- tients are enrolled in narrow-network insurance plans are likely to be more competitive than structurally identical markets with limited up- take of such plans. Difficulty in defining a “market” is a second

obstacle to applying the “structure-conduct- performance” paradigm. Markets defined nar- rowly (in terms of geography or provider type) will generally appear less competitive than those defined broadly. Markets with highly differenti- ated firms (for example, two hospitals located ten miles apart rather than across the street from one another, or one academic medical center and

doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.2021.00001 HEALTH AFFAIRS 40, NO. 9 (2021): 1386–1394 ©2021 Project HOPE— The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc.

Maximilian J. Pany ([email protected] hms.harvard.edu) is an MD- PhD candidate in health policy at Harvard Medical School and Harvard Business School, in Boston, Massachusetts.

Michael E. Chernew is the Leonard D. Schaeffer Professor of Health Care Policy in the Department of Health Care Policy, Harvard Medical School.

Leemore S. Dafny is the Bruce V. Rauner Professor of Business Administration at Harvard Business School and the Harvard Kennedy School, Harvard University, in Cambridge, Massachusetts.

1386 Health Affairs September 2021 40:9

Considering Health Spending

Downloaded from HealthAffairs.org on December 14, 2021. Copyright Project HOPE—The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc.

For personal use only. All rights reserved. Reuse permissions at HealthAffairs.org.

one community hospital) will be less competitive than those with the same number of firms that are more similar. These nuances limit the effec- tiveness of tying regulation to crude measures of concentration. Although market definitions can be tailored, doing so on a national scale is diffi- cult and requires more detailed data than are readily available. These challenges weaken the connection be-

tween market structure and profit margins or prices, making it likely that some hospitals in “unconcentrated” markets possess and exercise some market power. Thus, relying on market concentration–based triggers for regulation or antitrust policy, particularly when markets are defined broadly, is unlikely to effectively target many hospitals whose prices are elevated as a result of market power. This concern is not merely theoretical. Think-

tank proposals as well as two pieces of legislation recently introduced in Congress rely on mea- sures of market structure, such as provider mar- ket shares or the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI), to trigger regulatory action to promote competition in targeted markets. For instance, the Bipartisan Policy Center’s “Bipartisan Rx for America’s HealthCare” proposes that hospitals in markets with HHIs exceeding 4,000 and lo- cated in counties with populations at or above the US median be required to enter into nego- tiations with the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) to bring their HHI below 4,000 or have their prices capped at a percentage of Medicare Advantage rates.6 The Hospital Competition Act of 2019 (H.R. 506) would require hospitals with market shares of 15 percent or more in markets with HHIs exceeding 4,000 in urban areas and 5,000 in rural areas to accept Medicare rates from commercial payers.7 The Fair Care Act of 2019 (H.R. 1332) includes the same provision.8

Price regulation efforts such as these intend to prevent providers in uncompetitive markets from exercising their pricing power. Market structure–based triggers for price regulation are insufficient, however, if providers in struc- turally competitive markets nonetheless possess market power that allows them to demand higher prices without having to provide higher quality warranting those prices. Using a combination of more recent and more

comprehensive data than used in prior studies, we analyze variation in hospital prices after ad- justing for variation in area wages and relate the adjusted price levels to market concentration. We report two key findings. First, high-price hos- pitals, defined as those in the top quartile of the adjusted national price distribution, were preva- lent across the concentration spectrum. Specifi- cally, they were prevalent within all four concen-

tration categories we examined, which include the three categories used by antitrust regulators that are delineated by HHI thresholds of 1,500 and 2,500, and an additional policy-relevant cat- egory, delineated by an HHI threshold of 4,000. Second, the majority of these high-price hospi- tals are located in the bottom two categories, which are “unconcentrated” or “moderately con- centrated” markets, per the Horizontal Merger Guidelines of the FTC and Department of Jus- tice (DOJ).10

Our findings are relevant to current proposals to selectively regulate providers in highly con- centrated markets. This approach will leave a substantial number of high-price providers un- affected. The findings also illustrate the short- comings of relying too heavily on measures of market structure when evaluating potential trig- gers for regulatory or antitrust review in this sector, specifically if authorities rely on untail- ored, commonly used geographic market defi- nitions.

Conceptual Framework We divide providers into four categories, defined by price (low or high) and market concentration (low-to-moderate or high) (see exhibit A1 in the online appendix).11 Low-price providers, wheth- er in markets with low-to-moderate or high con- centration, typically do not generate concern as long as they are financially solvent. Existing pol- icy proposals tend to target high-price hospitals (or hospitals with high market shares) in con- centrated markets. Yet because of a range of in- stitutional features, including insurance, which shields patients from the price of care, informa- tion problems, and product differentiation based on location or reputation, many hospitals in low-concentration markets may have market power and thus charge high prices. In this article we document the prevalence of hospitals in the category of high price/low-to-moderate market concentration.We argue that policies to address high prices should be crafted to address those hospitals as well.

Study Data And Methods Data To measure hospital prices, we used 2017 claims data from the Health Care Cost Institute (HCCI)12 for all hospital inpatient and outpatient facility services delivered to adults ages 18–64 with commercial employer-sponsored health in- surance from one of three national insurers. This sample includes more than forty million individ- uals annually. To measure hospital market struc- ture, we calculated market HHIs using the num- ber of admissions reported by general acute care

September 2021 40:9 Health Affairs 1387 Downloaded from HealthAffairs.org on December 14, 2021.

Copyright Project HOPE—The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc. For personal use only. All rights reserved. Reuse permissions at HealthAffairs.org.

hospitals in the 2017 American Hospital Associ- ation (AHA) Annual Survey,13 together with Torch Insight data on system affiliation for each hospital.14

Measuring Hospital Prices Using HCCI data, we constructed separate inpatient facility and outpatient facility samples, in each case re- stricting the sample to facility claims of general acute care hospitals with valid service codes, pos- itive allowed amounts (the total paid for the ser- vice by insurer and patient), and appropriate place-of-service codes (see supplemental details in appendix section 2.1).11 We excluded non- group insurance claims, Medicare claims, and claims indicating secondary coverage.We identi- fied inpatient facility services by their diagnosis- related group (DRG) and outpatient facility ser- vices by their Current Procedural Terminology (CPT) code. For the purpose of price measure- ment, we treated distinct Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) Certification Numbers (CCNs) in distinct markets as unique hospitals. We adjusted market concentration measures for common hospital ownership, as discussed below. We aggregated claim lines to the patient-admission-hospital-DRG level in our inpatient facility sample and to the patient-visit- hospital-CPT-code level in our outpatient facility sample; the sum of allowed amounts is our mea- sure of price for each inpatient or outpatient facility visit. To adjust for geographic variation in area wages, a key input cost, we divided all prices by the Medicare wage index for the rele- vant market. Following the literature, we exclud- ed hospitals with fewer than fifty cases annually (at the hospital-market level) and excluded the top and bottom 1 percent of most expensive cases for each DRG or CPT code.15

To characterize price variation across hospi- tals, we first calculated an implied price index for each hospital in our inpatient facility and outpa- tient facility samples by repricing claims to their national service-specific means and dividing ob- served hospital spending by repriced hospital spending, using the services actually delivered by each hospital.16 This approach, used by the Institute of Medicine’s report on geographic var- iation17 and by the HCCI,18 among others, mea- sures how much prices at any given hospital de- viate from national average prices for the services delivered at that hospital. A value great- er than 1 implies that a particular hospital has relatively high prices, and a value less than 1 implies the opposite. Crucially, the implied price index reflects differences in service mix across hospitals. An advantage of this measure is that it allowed us to include a large sample of hospitals. The results were robust to other price indices based on fixed market baskets of services (see

appendix section 4.2.2 for details),11 but those approaches necessitated that we drop many hos- pitals that did not provide enough volume for some of the services in the market basket. Identifying High-Price Hospitals And

Their Volume Weidentified high-price hospitals irrespective of market by flagging hospitals in the upper quartile of the national wage index– adjusted price distribution in our HCCI samples. We used the number of inpatient facility admis- sions or outpatient facility visits, respectively, when calculating the share of inpatient facility or outpatient facility services delivered by high- price hospitals. Additional details, as well as sen- sitivity analyses that define “high-price” hospital using different national percentiles, are in the appendix.11

Measuring Hospital Market Structure To align with existing policy proposals, our primary market definition is the hospital referral region (HRR).7,8 Because one approach to expanding the reach of concentration-based policy pro- posals would be to narrow the market definition, we also report results using smaller market def- initions, specifically Metropolitan Statistical Areas (MSAs), commuting zones, and hospital service areas (HSAs). We constructed system- adjusted market-level HHIs by summing the squared market share of total hospital admis- sions attributable to each health care system in each market. These HHIs reflect the concentra- tion of market power that arises because hospi- tals belonging to the same health system typical- ly negotiate jointly with area insurers. In the appendix (section 4.2.5)11 we present sensitivity analyses that use the Agency for Healthcare Re- search and Quality’s 2018 Compendium of US Health Systems files, instead of Torch Insight data, to link hospitals to health care systems.19

We grouped markets by their HHIs into four policy-relevant categories of concentration. We began with the three categories used in antitrust analysis: markets classified by the FTC and DOJ as “unconcentrated” (HHI below 1,500), “mod- erately concentrated” (HHI between 1,500 and 2,500), and “concentrated” (HHI above 2,500).10 Based on language in recently pro- posed price regulation proposals,6–8 we further subdivided “concentrated” markets into those with an HHI score between 2,500 and 4,000 and those with an HHI above 4,000, yielding four categories. Limitations Our analysis had several limita-

tions. First, the HCCI data are a convenience sample of health care claims from three large insurers (Humana, Aetna, and UnitedHealth- care), not a random sample of all commercially insured enrollees in the US. In particular, our version of the data (HCCI 1.0) does not contain

Considering Health Spending

1388 Health Affairs September 2021 40:9 Downloaded from HealthAffairs.org on December 14, 2021.

Copyright Project HOPE—The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc. For personal use only. All rights reserved. Reuse permissions at HealthAffairs.org.

claims fromsmallerand regionalinsurers, which may pay different prices than do the large nation- al insurers, or from Blue Cross Blue Shield affili- ates, which have significant market share in most states.20 Although the HCCI data include claims from almost all hospitals registered with the AHA, they cover a smaller fraction of these hospitals after we applied our hospital case threshold (fifty claims). The prevalence of high- price hospitals across the concentration spec- trum may differ for hospitals excluded from our price measurement sample, which may have affected our prevalence estimates (see appendix section 2.4 for more information on included and excluded providers).11 The HCCI data do, however, cover more than a fourth of the private- ly insured US population across employers of all sizes.15 Because of the large sample size and be- cause they include provider identifiers (as op- posed to only market and service identifiers), the HCCI data are well suited for our study of cross-market variation in hospital prices. For these reasons, many related studies also use HCCI data.15,21–23 Because we used AHA, and not HCCI, data to measure market concentra- tion, our market structure measures did not de- pend on the number of hospitals captured in the HCCI data. Second, we defined hospitals within markets

at the CCN level for the purpose of price mea- surement. The CCN is an imperfect measure. Multiple hospitals can bill or report to Medicare under a single CCN, even if they are in distinct geographic markets. A single hospital may also split service lines into separate National Provid- er Identifiers for billing—and potentially price negotiation—purposes. Despite these limita- tions, we adopted this provider identifier be- cause it is used for payment by CMS and is there- fore regularly monitored and updated, and because other provider definitions have similar limitations. Our results were robust to measur- ing prices and volume at the level of billing-entity National Provider Identifiers instead of CCNs (see appendix section 4.2.4).11 In addition, we report results not only for the number of unique hospitals in each market concentration category but also for the number of admissions or visits in each category. These “volume-based analyses” are likely less sensitive to situations in which an organization splits service lines into subunits for billing purposes. However, the volume-based measures have a different limitation, in that they reflect only claims in our HCCI samples, which do not capture the full scope of business for any provider. Unfortunately, we did not observe volumes at the CCN level, and our volume mea- sures do not reflect case-mix (see appendix sec- tion 2.3).11

Fourth, we used an implied price measure that included all services actually delivered by each hospital in our sample. A limitation of this ap- proach is that hospital markups may vary by service line, and our approach did not hold the market basket of services constant across hospi- tals that offer different service lines. However, the main alternative, a price index measure that compares prices of a fixed basket of services across hospitals, has the drawbacks of capturing a smaller share of spending and greatly restrict- ing the sample of hospitals and markets that canbe analyzed without imputation. Theimplied approach and the market-basket approach are highly correlated.16 Appendix section 4.2.2 shows that our findings were robust to using a market basket approach.11

Fifth, following existing policy proposals and per common practice, we measured market con- centration using the HHI, which we constructed using the number of hospital admissions in the AHA data. (Note that these HHIs are highly cor- related [r > 0:95] with versions constructed us- ing total patient revenues or number of staffed beds). As discussed above, the HHI is an imper- fect measure of competition when providers of- fer differentiated products or market definitions are not tailored. In addition, we used the HHI based on inpatient facility admissions for anal- yses of both inpatient facility and outpatient facility prices. Although competition for outpa- tient facility services is different, these differenc- es largely arise because there are nonhospital providers offering outpatient facility services. As our sample was limited to hospital providers, HHIs constructed on the basis of inpatient facili- ty admissions are highly correlated with those constructed on the basis of outpatient facility visits (r > 0:86), and results using the two mea- sures were qualitatively similar (appendix sec- tion 4.2.1).11 We thus relied on HHIs based on inpatient facility admissions for simplicity. To the extent that there is a substantial number of other, nonhospital competitors for various out- patient facility service lines, markets currently classified as highly concentrated would be real- located to lower concentration categories if data on these additional competitors were included, reducing the potential reach of current pro- posals. Sixth, it is likely that geographic markets for

many services are much smaller than the HRR (for example, labor and delivery or acute cardiac care services). Indeed, some prior studies of the relationship between market structure and price have used much narrower geographic market definitions (for example, hospitals within a fif- teen-mile radius).15 Conversely, for some very specialized services (for example, transplants),

September 2021 40:9 Health Affairs 1389 Downloaded from HealthAffairs.org on December 14, 2021.

Copyright Project HOPE—The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc. For personal use only. All rights reserved. Reuse permissions at HealthAffairs.org.

HRRs may understate the breadth of the market. Some studies have eliminated quasi-arbitrary geographic boundaries by constructing hospi- tal-specific measures of competition, derived us- ing data on patients’ choices in all areas from which the hospital draws patients.24–26 Although these alternatives are likely preferable to a fixed geographic market definition for causal studies of the effect of competition on prices, policy typically relies on commonly available measures of market structure. Our primary analysis used the HRR because it is a common market defini- tion and is the definition used by existing pro- posals that specify a market definition.7,8 We show how our estimates are affected by defining geographic markets in terms of MSAs, commut- ing zones, and HSAs.11

Finally, many variables not included in our analysis (such as insurer market concentration) may affect the relationship between hospital market structure and hospital price. This omis- sion was deliberate—we did not estimate a causal relationship. In fact, our analysis highlights the flaws in relying on one predictor or correlate of the true outcome of interest.

Study Results Prevalence Of High-Price Hospitals We sought to investigate the proportion of high- price hospitals within each of four HHI concen- trationcategories.Definedas hospitals in thetop quartile of the national, area wage index–adjust-

ed price distribution, high-price hospitals were prevalent within each HHI category. Exhibit 1 shows that for inpatient services, high-price hos- pitals constituted 26.5 percent of hospitals in unconcentrated markets (HHI below 1,500), 20.9 percent in moderately concentrated mar- kets (HHI between 1,500 and 2,500), 24.3 per- cent in concentrated markets with HHI between 2,500 and 4,000, and 34.1 percent in concentrat- ed markets with HHIabove 4,000. Foroutpatient services, the proportions of high-price hospitals were 28.8, 22.8, 23.1, and 25.4 percent, respec- tively. These findings remained qualitatively similar for alternative definitions of “high-price” hospitals, hospital providers, and HHI measures (see sensitivity analyses in appendix section 4.2).11

Results weresimilar whenwe evaluatedservice volume rather the number of service providers, except for outpatient services, where high-price hospitals in unconcentrated markets garnered a lower share (see appendix section 3.1).11

Market Locations Of High-Price Hospitals We also examined the proportion of high-price hospitals across HHI categories (exhibit 2). High-price hospitals were more prevalent in markets with low-to-moderate concentration (HHI up to 2,500) versus high concentration (HHI above 2,500). Specifically, for inpatient services, 30.0 percent of high-price hospitals were located in unconcentrated markets, 28.4 percent in moderately concentrated mar- kets, 24.2 percent in concentrated markets with HHI between 2,500 and 4,000, and 17.4 percent in concentrated markets with HHI above 4,000. For outpatient services, 34.9 percent of high- price hospitals were located in unconcentrated markets, 27.5 percent in moderately concentrat- ed markets, 24.9 percent in concentrated mar- kets with HHI between 2,500 and 4,000, and 12.7 percent in concentrated markets with HHI exceeding 4,000. Likewise, most of the volume of high-price

hospitals was delivered in unconcentrated or moderately concentrated markets (see appendix section 3.1).11 For inpatient services, the share of volume delivered by high-price hospitals in mar- kets with HHI up to 2,500 was higher than the share of hospitals in those markets (69.0 percent of volume versus 58.4 percent of hospitals; exhibit 2 and appendix exhibit AR2). For out- patient services, the share of volume delivered by high-price hospitals in markets with HHI up to 2,500 was somewhat lower than the share of hospitals in those markets (59.1 percent ver- sus 62.4 percent; exhibit 2 and appendix ex- hibit AR2). Exhibits 3 and 4 show the cumulative distribu-

tion of high-price hospitals across HHI values for

Exhibit 1

Prevalence of high-price hospitals in the US within market concentration categories, 2017

Hospital market Herfindahl-Hirschman Index

<1,500 ≥1,500 to ≤2,500

>2,500 to ≤4,000 >4,000

No. of hospitals

Inpatient

High price 26.5% 20.9% 24.3% 34.1% 447 Not high price 73.5% 79.1% 75.7% 65.9% 1,340 No. of hospitals 505 608 445 229 1,787

Outpatient

High price 28.8% 22.8% 23.1% 25.4% 1,273 Not high price 71.2% 77.2% 76.9% 74.6% 3,816 No. of hospitals 1,541 1,535 1,374 639 5,089

SOURCE Authors’ analysis of Health Care Cost Institute data, 2017. NOTES Because this exhibit shows within-market concentration category proportions, column percentages sum to 100%, but row percentages do not. The number of markets (hospital referral regions) in each category is as follows. Inpatient: <1,500, n = 25; ≥1,500 to ≤2,500, n = 68; >2,500 to ≤4,000, n = 103; >4,000, n = 91. Outpatient: <1,500, n = 25; ≥1,500 to ≤2,500, n = 69; >2,500 to ≤4,000, n = 110; >4,000, n = 102. Number of hospitals and hospital prices are measured at the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) Certification Number (CCN)–market level in the 2017 Health Care Cost Institute data. High-price hospitals were defined as those in the upper quartile of the national wage index–adjusted price distribution in our inpatient or outpatient sample. Hospital market structure is measured at the system-adjusted CCN level in terms of total admissions recorded in the 2017 American Hospital Association Annual Survey. Hospitals are general acute care hospitals. See the text for additional details on sample construction.

Considering Health Spending

1390 Health Affairs September 2021 40:9 Downloaded from HealthAffairs.org on December 14, 2021.

Copyright Project HOPE—The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc. For personal use only. All rights reserved. Reuse permissions at HealthAffairs.org.

four geographic market definitions. These defi- nitions are, from the largest to the smallest individual markets, HRRs, MSAs, commuting zones, and HSAs. For both inpatient (exhibit 3) and outpatient (exhibit 4) services, the number of highly concentrated markets, and thus the prevalence of high-price hospitals within those markets, increased with each successively smaller market definition. For the narrowest market definition (the HSA, which is unconcen- trated only in very urban areas), the estimated prevalence of high-price hospitals in markets that were not highly concentrated shrank to 14.3 percent for inpatient services (exhibit 3) and to 23.1 percent for outpatient services (exhibit 4). For all other market definitions stud- ied, between a little more than a third and more than half of high-price hospitals were located in unconcentrated and moderately concentrated markets. These findings were qualitatively similar for

alternative definitions of “high-price” hospitals, hospital providers, and HHI measures (see ap- pendix section 4.2).11

Discussion Our analysis complements and extends the ex- isting literature on hospital price variation, which highlights variation within and across ge-

ographies and, more recently, within hospitals across insurers. Using claims data for approxi- mately one-fourth of the US commercially in- sured population in 2017, we constructed an in- patient and outpatient price index for each US

Exhibit 2

Prevalence of high-price hospitals in the US across market concentration categories, 2017

Hospital market Herfindahl-Hirschman Index

<1,500 ≥1,500 to ≤2,500

>2,500 to ≤4,000 >4,000

No. of hospitals

Inpatient

High price 30.0% 28.4% 24.2% 17.4% 447 Not high price 27.7% 35.9% 25.1% 11.3% 1,340 No. of hospitals 505 608 445 229 1,787

Outpatient

High price 34.9% 27.5% 24.9% 12.7% 1,273 Not high price 28.7% 31.1% 27.7% 12.5% 3,816 No. of hospitals 1,541 1,535 1,374 639 5,089

SOURCE Authors’ analysis of Health Care Cost Institute data, 2017. NOTES Because this exhibit shows across-market concentration category proportions, row percentages sum to 100% but column percentages do not. The number of markets (hospital referral regions) in each category is in the exhibit 1 notes. Number of hospitals and hospital prices are measured at the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) Certification Number (CCN)–market level in the 2017 Health Care Cost Institute data. High-price hospitals were defined as those in the upper quartile of the national wage index–adjusted price distribution in our inpatient or outpatient sample. Hospital market structure is measured at the system-adjusted CCN level in terms of total admissions recorded in the 2017 American Hospital Association Annual Survey. Hospitals are general acute care hospitals. See the text for additional details on sample construction.

Exhibit 3

Cumulative distribution of US hospitals with high inpatient prices across concentration thresholds for four common geographic market definitions, 2017

SOURCE Authors’ analysis of Health Care Cost Institute data, 2017. NOTES Vertical lines represent the market concentration thresholds used in the analysis: Herfindahl-Hirschman Indexes of 1,500, 2,500, and 4,000. Details on sample construction are in the exhibit 2 notes and the text.

September 2021 40:9 Health Affairs 1391 Downloaded from HealthAffairs.org on December 14, 2021.

Copyright Project HOPE—The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc. For personal use only. All rights reserved. Reuse permissions at HealthAffairs.org.

general acute care hospital with sufficient vol- ume in our sample and examined the relation- ship between the indices and the degree of hos- pital market concentration.We found that when we used the market definition common in policy proposals, most high-price inpatient and out- patient hospitals were not located in concentrat- ed markets; in fact, more than a quarter of all high-price hospitals were located in unconcen- trated markets, or those with HHIs below 1,500. Only 17.4 percent of all high-price hospitals providing inpatient services and only 12.7 per- cent of all high-price hospitals providing out- patient services were located in the most concen- trated HRR markets (those with HHI exceeding 4,0

Our website has a team of professional writers who can help you write any of your homework. They will write your papers from scratch. We also have a team of editors just to make sure all papers are of HIGH QUALITY & PLAGIARISM FREE. To make an Order you only need to click Ask A Question and we will direct you to our Order Page at WriteEdu. Then fill Our Order Form with all your assignment instructions. Select your deadline and pay for your paper. You will get it few hours before your set deadline.

Fill in all the assignment paper details that are required in the order form with the standard information being the page count, deadline, academic level and type of paper. It is advisable to have this information at hand so that you can quickly fill in the necessary information needed in the form for the essay writer to be immediately assigned to your writing project. Make payment for the custom essay order to enable us to assign a suitable writer to your order. Payments are made through Paypal on a secured billing page. Finally, sit back and relax.

Do you need an answer to this or any other questions?

Do you need help with this question?

Get assignment help from WriteEdu.com Paper Writing Website and forget about your problems.

WriteEdu provides custom & cheap essay writing 100% original, plagiarism free essays, assignments & dissertations.

With an exceptional team of professional academic experts in a wide range of subjects, we can guarantee you an unrivaled quality of custom-written papers.

Chat with us today! We are always waiting to answer all your questions.

Click here to Place your Order Now